Jump to content

James M. Malcomson: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Declining submission: v - Submission is improperly sourced (AFCH 0.9.1)
Provided DOIs/URLs/ISBNs/etc for footnotes as requested.
Line 18: Line 18:


==Career==
==Career==
Malcomson was lecturer, then senior lecturer, at the [[University of York]] (1972-85), Professor of Economics at the [[University of Southampton]] (1985-1999) and then statutory Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford and Fellow of All Souls College (1999-2013). He was elected Fellow of the [[British Academy]] in 2000 and Fellow of the [[Econometric Society]] in 2005. He chaired the [[The_Office_of_Health_Economics|Office of Health Economics]] Commission on Competition in the NHS, 2011-12<ref>''Competition in the NHS'', Report of the Office of Health Economics Commission, January 2012</ref> and served as a member of the [[Review_Body_on_Doctors'_and_Dentists'_Remuneration|Review Body on Doctors’ and Dentists’ Remuneration]], 2015-2021.<ref>https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/1005003/DDRB_2021_Web_Accessible_v2.pdf p. iii. Retrieved 17 March 2023</ref>
Malcomson was lecturer, then senior lecturer, at the [[University of York]] (1972-85), Professor of Economics at the [[University of Southampton]] (1985-1999) and then statutory Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford and Fellow of All Souls College (1999-2013). He was elected Fellow of the [[British Academy]] in 2000 and Fellow of the [[Econometric Society]] in 2005. He chaired the [[The_Office_of_Health_Economics|Office of Health Economics]] Commission on Competition in the NHS, 2011-12<ref>''Competition in the NHS'', Report of the Office of Health Economics Commission, January 2012</ref> and served as a member of the [[Review_Body_on_Doctors'_and_Dentists'_Remuneration|Review Body on Doctors’ and Dentists’ Remuneration]], 2015-2021.<ref>https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/1005003/DDRB_2021_Web_Accessible_v2.pdf p. iii. Retrieved 17 March 2023</ref>


==Research==
==Research==
Malcomson’s early research analysed vintage effects in investment, especially the implications for obsolescence, replacement and utilisation of capital equipment and the effects of tax policy on these. He derived rigorous theoretical models of optimal investment and replacement that do not rely on stationarity [1],<ref>Morton I. Kamien and Nancy L. Schwartz, ''Dynamic Optimization'' (2nd edition, Dover, 2012, p. 361)</ref> showed how optimal policies relate to simple rules, and derived analytic results for the effects of changes in tax policy on investment and replacement [3].<ref>Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), ''Who's Who in Economics'' (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003)</ref> He also devised ways to estimate such models empirically without imposing stationarity, an essential step in predicting the short-run effects of tax policy changes [2],<ref>E. Bjørn, ''Taxation, Technology, and the User Cost of Capital'' (Elsevier, 1989, p. 122)</ref><ref>Terry Barker, Paul Ekins and Nick Johnstone (eds.), ''Global Warming and Energy Demand'' (Routledge, 1994, p. 124)</ref>. He additionally explored dynamic inconsistency in government policies [6],<ref>Keith Blackburn and Michael Christensen, "Monetary policy and policy credibility: theories and evidence", ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 27, 1989, p. 12</ref> the [[Laffer Curve]] [7],<ref>John Kay, "Tax policy: a survey", ''Economic Journal'', 100, 1990, p. 35</ref> and the impact of trade unions [9].<ref>Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, ''Labor Economics'' (MIT Press, 2014, pp. 755, 780)</ref>
Malcomson’s early research analysed vintage effects in investment, especially the implications for obsolescence, replacement and utilisation of capital equipment and the effects of tax policy on these. He derived rigorous theoretical models of optimal investment and replacement that do not rely on stationarity [1],<ref>Morton I. Kamien and Nancy L. Schwartz, ''Dynamic Optimization'' (2nd edition, Dover, 2012, p. 361)</ref> showed how optimal policies relate to simple rules, and derived analytic results for the effects of changes in tax policy on investment and replacement [3].<ref>Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), ''Who's Who in Economics'' (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003)</ref> He also devised ways to estimate such models empirically without imposing stationarity, an essential step in predicting the short-run effects of tax policy changes [2],<ref>E. Bjørn, ''Taxation, Technology, and the User Cost of Capital'' (Elsevier, 1989, p. 122)</ref><ref>Terry Barker, Paul Ekins and Nick Johnstone (eds.), ''Global Warming and Energy Demand'' (Routledge, 1994, p. 124)</ref>. He additionally explored dynamic inconsistency in government policies [6],<ref>Keith Blackburn and Michael Christensen, "Monetary policy and policy credibility: theories and evidence", ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 27, 1989, p. 12</ref> the [[Laffer Curve]] [7],<ref>John Kay, "Tax policy: a survey", ''Economic Journal'', 100, 1990, p. 35</ref> and the impact of trade unions [9].<ref>Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, ''Labor Economics'' (MIT Press, 2014, pp. 755, 780)</ref>


Malcomson’s empirical research on production convinced him of the need for economists to understand better the labour side of the production process and much of his more recent research has been directed towards that.<ref>Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), ''Who's Who in Economics'' (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003)</ref> One of his main concerns has been with different ways of motivating employees when important aspects of performance are not easily specified in the employment contract and their implications: high pay coupled with the threat of dismissal for unsatisfactory performance ([[Efficiency wage|efficiency wages]]) [4]<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 123)</ref><ref>Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 929)</ref>, competition for promotion [5],<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 122)</ref><ref>Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), ''Handbook of Labor Economics'', Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, pp. 2401-2)</ref><ref>Robert Gibbons and John Roberts, "Economic theories of incentives in organizations" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 67)</ref><ref>Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 528-9)</ref> [[Tournament_theory|tournaments]] [8]<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 89)</ref> and repeated interaction over time [10],<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 98)</ref> which "showed that the optimal long-term contract can be replicated by a sequence of optimal static contracts when the agent's saving decision can be controlled by the principal."<ref>Jean-Jacques Laffont and David Martimort, ''The Theory of Incentives'' (Princeton University Press, 2002, pp. 332-3)</ref> With [[W. Bentley MacLeod]], he characterized the full set of outcomes that can be sustained in such repeated [[Principal–agent problem|principal-agent]] contexts [12], described as "the "classic" relational contract model"<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 267)</ref> and "(t)he most complete analysis of [[Relational_contract|relational contracts]] under symmetric information".<ref>Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, ''Contract Theory'' (MIT Press, 2005), p. 462)</ref> Together they also showed that tournaments and competition for promotion can provide effective methods of motivation provided agent-employees are sufficiently heterogeneous in their abilities, a system that “mimics a remarkable number of the features of actual job ladders in internal labor markets” <ref>Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, ''Economics, Organization and Management'' (Prentice-Hall, 1992, p. 374)</ref> [11]. Performance-related bonuses are effective even when agent-employees are homogeneous but may result in less efficient outcomes than efficiency wages when prospective employees are plentiful relative to jobs [18].<ref>Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), ''Handbook of Labor Economics'', Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, p. 2390)</ref> But when employees differ in abilities, competition for promotion may be open to influence activities and so distort allocation of employees to more senior jobs [21]<ref>Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, ''Contract Theory'' (MIT Press, 2005, p. 316)</ref><ref>Edward P. Lazear and Paul Oyer, "Personnel Economics" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 483, 495)</ref><ref>Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 532)</ref> and efficient outcomes in the future prevent full separation of abilities when differences are sufficiently fine [26] in which "Malcomson provides a general analysis of relational contracts with persistent private information. He shows that full revelation of information is inconsistent with continuation payoffs being on the Pareto frontier, and therefore it generalizes the observation that asymmetric information leads to conflict in relational contracts."<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 331)</ref> This approach has been taken up in the subsequent literature.<ref>David Martimort, Aggey Semenov and Lars Stole, "A theory of contracts with limited enforcement", ''Review of Economic Studies'', 84, 2017, p. 820</ref> These results have implications for dual economies [18] and cyclical behavior [14], in which the "interplay between competition and relational contracts also has implications for output over the business cycle".<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 275)</ref> The implications for labour markets are surveyed in [15] and, more completely, in [19]<ref>Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, ''Labor Economics'' (MIT Press, 2014, p. 325)</ref> and those for economic organizations in [25].
Malcomson’s empirical research on production convinced him of the need for economists to understand better the labour side of the production process and much of his more recent research has been directed towards that.<ref>Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), ''Who's Who in Economics'' (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003)</ref> One of his main concerns has been with different ways of motivating employees when important aspects of performance are not easily specified in the employment contract and their implications: high pay coupled with the threat of dismissal for unsatisfactory performance ([[Efficiency wage|efficiency wages]]) [4]<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 123)</ref><ref>Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 929)</ref>, competition for promotion [5],<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 122)</ref><ref>Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), ''Handbook of Labor Economics'', Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, pp. 2401-2)</ref><ref>Robert Gibbons and John Roberts, "Economic theories of incentives in organizations" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 67)</ref><ref>Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 528-9)</ref> [[Tournament_theory|tournaments]] [8]<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 89)</ref> and repeated interaction over time [10],<ref>Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), ''Advances in Economic Theory'' (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 98)</ref> which "showed that the optimal long-term contract can be replicated by a sequence of optimal static contracts when the agent's saving decision can be controlled by the principal."<ref>Jean-Jacques Laffont and David Martimort, ''The Theory of Incentives'' (Princeton University Press, 2002, pp. 332-3)</ref> With [[W. Bentley MacLeod]], he characterized the full set of outcomes that can be sustained in such repeated [[Principal–agent problem|principal-agent]] contexts [12], described as "the "classic" relational contract model"<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 267)</ref> and "(t)he most complete analysis of [[Relational_contract|relational contracts]] under symmetric information".<ref>Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, ''Contract Theory'' (MIT Press, 2005), p. 462)</ref> Together they also showed that tournaments and competition for promotion can provide effective methods of motivation provided agent-employees are sufficiently heterogeneous in their abilities, a system that “mimics a remarkable number of the features of actual job ladders in internal labor markets” <ref>Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, ''Economics, Organization and Management'' (Prentice-Hall, 1992, p. 374)</ref> [11]. Performance-related bonuses are effective even when agent-employees are homogeneous but may result in less efficient outcomes than efficiency wages when prospective employees are plentiful relative to jobs [18].<ref>Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), ''Handbook of Labor Economics'', Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, p. 2390)</ref> But when employees differ in abilities, competition for promotion may be open to influence activities and so distort allocation of employees to more senior jobs [21]<ref>Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, ''Contract Theory'' (MIT Press, 2005, p. 316)</ref><ref>Edward P. Lazear and Paul Oyer, "Personnel Economics" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 483, 495)</ref><ref>Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 532)</ref> and efficient outcomes in the future prevent full separation of abilities when differences are sufficiently fine [26] in which "Malcomson provides a general analysis of relational contracts with persistent private information. He shows that full revelation of information is inconsistent with continuation payoffs being on the Pareto frontier, and therefore it generalizes the observation that asymmetric information leads to conflict in relational contracts."<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 331)</ref> This approach has been taken up in the subsequent literature.<ref>David Martimort, Aggey Semenov and Lars Stole, "A theory of contracts with limited enforcement", ''Review of Economic Studies'', 84, 2017, p. 820</ref> These results have implications for dual economies [18] and cyclical behavior [14], in which the "interplay between competition and relational contracts also has implications for output over the business cycle".<ref>W. Bentley MacLeod, ''Advanced Microeconomics'' (MIT Press, 2022, p. 275)</ref> The implications for labour markets are surveyed in [15] and, more completely, in [19]<ref>Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, ''Labor Economics'' (MIT Press, 2014, p. 325)</ref> and those for economic organizations in [25].


Other research with W. Bentley MacLeod has shown that the types of contracts used in many practical situations have properties that theory suggests are appropriate for protecting investments in general and specific assets [13].<ref>Ilya Segal and Michael D. Whinston, "Property rights" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 129, 138)</ref><ref>Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 937)</ref> Research with other co-authors has shown how time-serving apprenticeships can mitigate incentive issues in training [22]<ref>Jane Humphries, ''Childhood and Child Labour in the British Industrial Revolution'' (Cambridge University Press, 2010, pp. 285-288)</ref> and the role for not-for-profit providers in provision of public sector services [27].<ref>Mathias Dewatripont and Jean Tirole, ''The Morality of Markets'' (ECARES, 2022, p. 36)</ref> Malcomson also analysed forms of contract appropriate for the provision of health services [23]<ref>Kurt R. Brekke, Robert Nuscheler, Odd Rune Straume, "Gatekeeping in health care", ''Journal of Health Economics'', 26(1), 2007, p. 152</ref><ref>Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics'' (Oxford University Press, 2020)</ref>, [24]<ref>Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics'' (Oxford University Press, 2020)</ref> and, most notably, the quality of care [16] and [17], developments surveyed in [20].<ref>Joseph P. Newhouse, ''Pricing the Priceless'' (MIT Press, 2002, pp. 93-98)</ref>
Other research with W. Bentley MacLeod has shown that the types of contracts used in many practical situations have properties that theory suggests are appropriate for protecting investments in general and specific assets [13].<ref>Ilya Segal and Michael D. Whinston, "Property rights" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 129, 138)</ref><ref>Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), ''Handbook of Organizational Economics'' (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 937)</ref> Research with other co-authors has shown how time-serving apprenticeships can mitigate incentive issues in training [22]<ref>Jane Humphries, ''Childhood and Child Labour in the British Industrial Revolution'' (Cambridge University Press, 2010, pp. 285-288)</ref> and the role for not-for-profit providers in provision of public sector services [27].<ref>Mathias Dewatripont and Jean Tirole, ''The Morality of Markets'' (ECARES, 2022, p. 36)
</ref> Malcomson also analysed forms of contract appropriate for the provision of health services [23]<ref>Kurt R. Brekke, Robert Nuscheler, Odd Rune Straume, "Gatekeeping in health care", ''Journal of Health Economics'', 26(1), 2007, p. 152</ref><ref>Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics'' (Oxford University Press, 2020)</ref>, [24]<ref>Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics'' (Oxford University Press, 2020)</ref> and, most notably, the quality of care [16] and [17], developments surveyed in [20].<ref>Joseph P. Newhouse, ''Pricing the Priceless'' (MIT Press, 2002, pp. 93-98)</ref>


==Personal life==
==Personal life==
Malcomson is married to the social gerontologist Dr Sally Richards.<ref>''Who's Who 2023'' (Bloomsbury, 2022)</ref> They live in Oxford.
Malcomson is married to the social gerontologist Dr Sally Richards.<ref>''Who's Who 2023'' (Bloomsbury, 2022)

https://www.bloomsbury.com/uk/whos-who-2023-9781472991287/</ref> They live in Oxford.


== References ==
== References ==

Revision as of 16:04, 21 November 2023

  • Comment: Can you please provide DOIs/URLs/ISBNs/etc for these footnotes? This is just going to keep sitting in the queue forever because it's going to take so long to review. Make it easier on us by giving fuller citations, which you can do easily by using the automatic citation tool in Visual Editor (click "cite", then "automatic", then dump in the relevant doi/isbn). asilvering (talk) 20:33, 4 August 2023 (UTC)
  • Comment: May be notable but much of the content is unsourced and/or needs secondary sources. S0091 (talk) 16:11, 16 March 2023 (UTC)

James Malcomson is a British-Irish economist. He is Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford[1] and Emeritus Fellow of All Souls College.[2] He is a specialist in the fields of labour and contract theory.

Education

Following graduation with a BA in Economics at the University of Cambridge (Gonville and Caius College) in 1967, Malcomson studied for a doctorate in Economics at Harvard University, which he completed in 1973 with a thesis supervised by the Nobel laureate Wassily Leontief.

Career

Malcomson was lecturer, then senior lecturer, at the University of York (1972-85), Professor of Economics at the University of Southampton (1985-1999) and then statutory Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford and Fellow of All Souls College (1999-2013). He was elected Fellow of the British Academy in 2000 and Fellow of the Econometric Society in 2005. He chaired[3] the Office of Health Economics Commission on Competition in the NHS, 2011-12[4] and served as a member of the Review Body on Doctors’ and Dentists’ Remuneration, 2015-2021.[5]

Research

Malcomson’s early research analysed vintage effects in investment, especially the implications for obsolescence, replacement and utilisation of capital equipment and the effects of tax policy on these. He derived rigorous theoretical models of optimal investment and replacement that do not rely on stationarity [1],[6] showed how optimal policies relate to simple rules, and derived analytic results for the effects of changes in tax policy on investment and replacement [3].[7] He also devised ways to estimate such models empirically without imposing stationarity, an essential step in predicting the short-run effects of tax policy changes [2],[8][9]. He additionally explored dynamic inconsistency in government policies [6],[10] the Laffer Curve [7],[11] and the impact of trade unions [9].[12]

Malcomson’s empirical research on production convinced him of the need for economists to understand better the labour side of the production process and much of his more recent research has been directed towards that.[13] One of his main concerns has been with different ways of motivating employees when important aspects of performance are not easily specified in the employment contract and their implications: high pay coupled with the threat of dismissal for unsatisfactory performance (efficiency wages) [4][14][15], competition for promotion [5],[16][17][18][19] tournaments [8][20] and repeated interaction over time [10],[21] which "showed that the optimal long-term contract can be replicated by a sequence of optimal static contracts when the agent's saving decision can be controlled by the principal."[22] With W. Bentley MacLeod, he characterized the full set of outcomes that can be sustained in such repeated principal-agent contexts [12], described as "the "classic" relational contract model"[23] and "(t)he most complete analysis of relational contracts under symmetric information".[24] Together they also showed that tournaments and competition for promotion can provide effective methods of motivation provided agent-employees are sufficiently heterogeneous in their abilities, a system that “mimics a remarkable number of the features of actual job ladders in internal labor markets” [25] [11]. Performance-related bonuses are effective even when agent-employees are homogeneous but may result in less efficient outcomes than efficiency wages when prospective employees are plentiful relative to jobs [18].[26] But when employees differ in abilities, competition for promotion may be open to influence activities and so distort allocation of employees to more senior jobs [21][27][28][29] and efficient outcomes in the future prevent full separation of abilities when differences are sufficiently fine [26] in which "Malcomson provides a general analysis of relational contracts with persistent private information. He shows that full revelation of information is inconsistent with continuation payoffs being on the Pareto frontier, and therefore it generalizes the observation that asymmetric information leads to conflict in relational contracts."[30] This approach has been taken up in the subsequent literature.[31] These results have implications for dual economies [18] and cyclical behavior [14], in which the "interplay between competition and relational contracts also has implications for output over the business cycle".[32] The implications for labour markets are surveyed in [15] and, more completely, in [19][33] and those for economic organizations in [25].

Other research with W. Bentley MacLeod has shown that the types of contracts used in many practical situations have properties that theory suggests are appropriate for protecting investments in general and specific assets [13].[34][35] Research with other co-authors has shown how time-serving apprenticeships can mitigate incentive issues in training [22][36] and the role for not-for-profit providers in provision of public sector services [27].[37] Malcomson also analysed forms of contract appropriate for the provision of health services [23][38][39], [24][40] and, most notably, the quality of care [16] and [17], developments surveyed in [20].[41]

Personal life

Malcomson is married to the social gerontologist Dr Sally Richards.[42] They live in Oxford.

References

  1. ^ "James Malcomson". www.economics.ox.ac.uk. Retrieved 2023-08-04.
  2. ^ "Professor James Malcomson | All Souls College". www.asc.ox.ac.uk. Retrieved 2023-08-04.
  3. ^ "New OHE Commission on Competition in the NHS - OHE". OHE - Leading intellectual authority on global health economics. 2011-02-14. Retrieved 2023-11-21.
  4. ^ Office of Health Economics Commission on Competition in the NHSCompetition in the NHS, Report of the Office of Health Economics Commission, January 2012. https://www.ohe.org/publications/report-office-health-economics-commission-competition-nhs/
  5. ^ https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/1005003/DDRB_2021_Web_Accessible_v2.pdf p. iii. Retrieved 17 March 2023
  6. ^ Morton I. Kamien and Nancy L. Schwartz, Dynamic Optimization (2nd edition, Dover, 2012, p. 361) ISBN 9780486488561 https://store.doverpublications.com/048648856x.html
  7. ^ Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), Who's Who in Economics (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003) ISBN: 978 1 84064 992 5 https://www.e-elgar.com/shop/gbp/who-s-who-in-economics-fourth-edition-9781840649925.html
  8. ^ E. Bjørn, Taxation, Technology, and the User Cost of Capital (Elsevier, 1989, p. 122) ISBN: 978-0-444-87490-0 ISSN: 0573-8555 https://www.sciencedirect.com/bookseries/contributions-to-economic-analysis/vol/182/suppl/C
  9. ^ Terry Barker, Paul Ekins and Nick Johnstone (eds.), Global Warming and Energy Demand (Routledge, 1994, p. 124) eBook ISBN 9780203983645 https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203983645
  10. ^ Keith Blackburn and Michael Christensen, "Monetary policy and policy credibility: theories and evidence", Journal of Economic Literature, 27, 1989, p. 12 ISSN 0022-0515 https://www.jstor.org/stable/2726940
  11. ^ John Kay, "Tax policy: a survey", Economic Journal, 100, 1990, p. 35 ISSN 0013-0133 https://doi.org/10.2307/2233594
  12. ^ Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, Labor Economics (MIT Press, 2014, pp. 755, 780) ISBN 9780262027700 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262027700/labor-economics/
  13. ^ Mark Blaug and Howard Vane (eds.), Who's Who in Economics (4th edition), (Edward Elgar, 2003) ISBN: 978 1 84064 992 5 https://www.e-elgar.com/shop/gbp/who-s-who-in-economics-fourth-edition-9781840649925.html
  14. ^ Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 123) Online ISBN 9781139052054 https://doi.org/10.1017/CCOL0521340446 https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/19C16ACE4A35CB03AA5B4C89E69C20FE/9781139052054c03_p71-156_CBO.pdf/theory_of_contracts.pdf
  15. ^ Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 929) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  16. ^ Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 122) Online ISBN 9781139052054 https://doi.org/10.1017/CCOL0521340446  https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/19C16ACE4A35CB03AA5B4C89E69C20FE/9781139052054c03_p71-156_CBO.pdf/theory_of_contracts.pdf
  17. ^ Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, pp. 2401-2) ISBN: 978-0-444-50188-2 https://www.sciencedirect.com/handbook/handbook-of-labor-economics/vol/3/part/PB
  18. ^ Robert Gibbons and John Roberts, "Economic theories of incentives in organizations" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 67) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  19. ^ Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 528-9) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  20. ^ Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 89) Online ISBN 9781139052054 https://doi.org/10.1017/CCOL0521340446  https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/19C16ACE4A35CB03AA5B4C89E69C20FE/9781139052054c03_p71-156_CBO.pdf/theory_of_contracts.pdf
  21. ^ Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmström, "The theory of contracts" in Truman F. Bewley (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory (Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 98) Online ISBN 9781139052054 https://doi.org/10.1017/CCOL0521340446  https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/19C16ACE4A35CB03AA5B4C89E69C20FE/9781139052054c03_p71-156_CBO.pdf/theory_of_contracts.pdf
  22. ^ Jean-Jacques Laffont and David Martimort, The Theory of Incentives (Princeton University Press, 2002, pp. 332-3) ISBN 9780691091846 https://press.princeton.edu/books/paperback/9780691091846/the-theory-of-incentives
  23. ^ W. Bentley MacLeod, Advanced Microeconomics (MIT Press, 2022, p. 267) ISBN 9780262046879 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262046879/advanced-microeconomics-for-contract-institutional-and-organizational-economics/
  24. ^ Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, Contract Theory (MIT Press, 2005), p. 462) ISBN 9780262025768 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262025768/contract-theory/
  25. ^ Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, Economics, Organization and Management (Prentice-Hall, 1992, p. 374) ISBN 9780132246507 https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:152523816
  26. ^ Robert Gibbons and Michael Waldman, "Careers in organizations: theories and evidence" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3B (Elsevier, 1999, p. 2390) ISBN: 978-0-444-50188-2 https://www.sciencedirect.com/handbook/handbook-of-labor-economics/vol/3/part/PB
  27. ^ Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, Contract Theory (MIT Press, 2005, p. 316) ISBN 9780262025768 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262025768/contract-theory/
  28. ^ Edward P. Lazear and Paul Oyer, "Personnel Economics" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 483, 495) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  29. ^ Michael Waldman, "Theory and evidence in internal labor markets" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 532) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  30. ^ W. Bentley MacLeod, Advanced Microeconomics (MIT Press, 2022, p. 331) ISBN 9780262046879 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262046879/advanced-microeconomics-for-contract-institutional-and-organizational-economics/
  31. ^ David Martimort, Aggey Semenov and Lars Stole, "A theory of contracts with limited enforcement", Review of Economic Studies, 84, 2017, p. 820
  32. ^ W. Bentley MacLeod, Advanced Microeconomics (MIT Press, 2022, p. 275) ISBN 9780262046879 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262046879/advanced-microeconomics-for-contract-institutional-and-organizational-economics/
  33. ^ Pierre Cahuc. Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg, Labor Economics (MIT Press, 2014, p. 325) ISBN 9780262027700 https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262027700/labor-economics/
  34. ^ Ilya Segal and Michael D. Whinston, "Property rights" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 129, 138) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  35. ^ Lewis A. Kornhauser and W. Bentley MacLeod, "Contracts between legal persons" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 937) ISBN 9780691132792 https://press.princeton.edu/books/ebook/9781400845354/the-handbook-of-organizational-economics
  36. ^ Jane Humphries, Childhood and Child Labour in the British Industrial Revolution (Cambridge University Press, 2010, pp. 285-288) Online ISBN 9780511780455 https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511780455
  37. ^ Mathias Dewatripont and Jean Tirole, The Morality of Markets (ECARES, 2022, p. 36) https://ideas.repec.org/p/eca/wpaper/2013-351283.html
  38. ^ Kurt R. Brekke, Robert Nuscheler, Odd Rune Straume, "Gatekeeping in health care", Journal of Health Economics, 26(1), 2007, p. 152 ISSN: 0167-6296 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2006.04.004
  39. ^ Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics (Oxford University Press, 2020) eISBN 9780190902186 doi 10.1093/acref/9780190902179.001.0001https://www.oxfordreference.com/display/10.1093/acref/9780190902179.001.0001/acref-9780190902179-e-61?rskey=AtYUK0&result=39
  40. ^ Ching-to Albert Ma and Henry Y. Mak, "Incentives in healthcare payment systems" in Andrew Jones (ed.), The Oxford Encyclopedia of Health Economics (Oxford University Press, 2020) eISBN 9780190902186 doi 10.1093/acref/9780190902179.001.0001https://www.oxfordreference.com/display/10.1093/acref/9780190902179.001.0001/acref-9780190902179-e-61?rskey=AtYUK0&result=39
  41. ^ Joseph P. Newhouse, Pricing the Priceless (MIT Press, 2002, pp. 93-98) ISBN 9780262640589https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262640589/pricing-the-priceless/
  42. ^ Who's Who 2023 (Bloomsbury, 2022) ISBN 9781472991287 https://www.bloomsbury.com/uk/whos-who-2023-9781472991287/